The most revolutionary upheavals took place in the countryside

Max Roder­mund

2 Octo­ber 2024

Expe­ri­en­ced coope­ra­tive farmers pass on their know­ledge to young people. Source: Dietz Verlag Berlin / ADN, 1985.

The bour­geois trans­for­ma­tion of agri­cul­ture in Germany in the begin­ning of the 19th century – known as the “Prus­sian path” – was unique in that it combi­ned the deve­lo­p­ment of the capi­ta­list mode of produc­tion with elements of feudal subor­di­na­tion. To free them­sel­ves of feudal burdens, German peasants had to pay 1.8 billion marks and cede 425,169 hecta­res of land to the Junkers, the landed nobi­lity. In the course of the century, land­less farm labou­rers grew to become the largest social group in the coun­try­side. Even after servants’ regu­la­ti­ons had offi­ci­ally been repea­led after the 1918 Novem­ber Revo­lu­tion, they often remained in prac­tice. These regu­la­ti­ons permit­ted the corpo­ral punish­ment of farm labou­rers, prohi­bi­ted them from leaving the farms unan­noun­ced and forbade trade union orga­ni­sa­tion. The econo­mic­ally and poli­ti­cally domi­nant role of the reac­tion­ary Junker class prolon­ged the lawless, prostrate situa­tion of the rural population.

The land reform: Junkers’ lands in peasants’ hands

The 1945/46 land reform in East Germany can only be unders­tood against this back­ground. It was not only a response to the war-dama­ged and thoroughly devas­ta­ted agri­cul­tu­ral produc­tion, it also put an end to the semi-feudal Junker rule. When asked why the land reform crea­ted new private property instead of natio­na­li­zing the land and socia­li­sing agri­cul­ture, Walter Ulbricht, the first secre­tary of the gover­ning SED gave a far-sigh­ted answer in 1947: “It might suit you, gentle­men, to keep the large estates intact so that you can later return them to the hands of the old owners! No, our course is diffe­rent: we are acting in such a way that the large estates are comple­tely divi­ded up so that there will never again be a large landow­ner in Germany who can get this land back.”

With the help of land reform commis­si­ons, the rural popu­la­tion actively enforced expro­pria­ti­ons and the redis­tri­bu­tion of land them­sel­ves. 3.3 million hecta­res (around a third of the total agri­cul­tu­ral and forestry land in the Soviet Occu­pa­tion Zone) were expro­pria­ted. A good 75% of this came from expro­pria­ted private estates with more than 100 hecta­res of usable land. Almost 2.2 million hecta­res of the land reform fund were distri­bu­ted prima­rily to land­less farmers, refu­gees, and small­hol­ders. The land owner­ship struc­ture in East Germany had chan­ged radi­cally. The hando­ver of the title deeds for the allo­ca­ted land became a day of cele­bra­tion in the villages.

The Asso­cia­tion of Mutual Farmers‘ Aid, machine lending stati­ons, and the Demo­cra­tic Farmers’ Party formed the orga­ni­sa­tio­nal basis for the demo­cra­tis­a­tion of the villa­ges and the deve­lo­p­ment of coope­ra­tive produc­tion rela­ti­onships among the new farmers even before the DDR was foun­ded in 1949.

The cooperative movement: “From me to we”

In 1952, there were a total of 871,724 farms in the DDR, of which only 28,473 were state farms. Toge­ther they farmed around 6.5 million hecta­res of agri­cul­tu­ral land. The average size of a farm was about 7.5 hecta­res. A quar­ter of the 8 million labou­rers in the DDR worked in agri­cul­ture at that time.

In order to increase the supply of food and raw mate­ri­als and for a more effi­ci­ent labour force, over­co­ming the small-scale produc­tion rela­ti­ons crea­ted by the land reform soon moved onto the agenda. Howe­ver, this issue remained unre­sol­ved as long as the natio­nal ques­tion was not finally addres­sed in Germany. The East German histo­rian Kurt Goss­wei­ler wrote, “The urgent need to increase the agri­cul­tu­ral yield posed a chall­enge for the DDR leader­ship: to open the way to large-scale agri­cul­ture, either in a capi­ta­list or a socia­list manner.” The fail­ure of the stra­tegy for a unified, demo­cra­tic and non-aligned Germany made it neces­sary to push ahead with a sove­reign econo­mic and secu­rity policy deve­lo­p­ment that was inde­pen­dent of the West. The second SED Party Confe­rence in 1952 paved the way for the forma­tion of co-opera­ti­ves: Land­writ­schaft­li­che Produk­ti­ons­ge­nos­sen­schaf­ten, LPG (“agri­cul­tu­ral produc­tion coope­ra­ti­ves”). This process from 1952 to 1960 is still used by bour­geois histo­ri­ans today as key evidence of the unde­mo­cra­tic nature of the “SED dicta­tor­ship” under the catch­phrase “forced collectivisation”.

In fact, against the back­ground of econo­mic deve­lo­p­ment requi­re­ments, the task was to bring about a huge uphe­aval in the farmers’ way of working, living, and thin­king in the shor­test possi­ble time and to deve­lop the neces­sary struc­tures for large-scale agri­cul­tu­ral produc­tion. This process could not be achie­ved without the active parti­ci­pa­tion of the vast majo­rity of farmers. In 1952, it was still incon­ceiva­ble for many of them to give up the form of inde­pen­dent farming that had matu­red over gene­ra­ti­ons. Many were dismis­sive, others took a wait-and-see approach. The long-term pros­pects of the DDR and socia­list recon­s­truc­tion seemed just as uncer­tain to them as the promise of higher produc­ti­vity in co-opera­tive farming. It was the small farms, farm labou­rers and new farmers who usually had the grea­test econo­mic diffi­cul­ties and at the same time had fewer strong ties to their land, making it easier to persuade them to join the LPG.

The cons­truc­tion of socia­lism was still in its infancy in the DDR and Eastern Europe. An atmo­sphere of coun­ter­re­vo­lu­tion was inci­ted and exacer­ba­ted by the West – in 1953 in the DDR and in 1956 in Hungary and Poland. Against this back­drop, it was not only in the DDR that fierce dispu­tes repea­tedly erupted over the rela­ti­onship between the volun­t­ary nature of co-opera­ti­ves and their targe­ted promo­tion by the state. In 1953, the SED published a self-criti­cism and deci­ded to reduce the pres­sure to form coope­ra­ti­ves as part of a compre­hen­sive “New Course” policy. At the same time, propo­sals such as cancel­ling state deve­lo­p­ment incen­ti­ves and subsi­dies for coope­ra­ti­ves, as had been deci­ded in Poland, for exam­ple, were shar­ply rejec­ted. In addi­tion, those forces that actively sabo­ta­ged the deve­lo­p­ment towards socia­list agri­cul­ture had to be combated.

In the spring of 1960, a new impluse was given to convince the last indi­vi­dual farmers to join the coope­ra­tive. Groups orga­nised by the poli­ti­cal parties and mass orga­ni­sa­ti­ons of the Natio­nal Front travel­led to the villa­ges toge­ther to discuss the issue with the farmers. Almost all of them signed up to join the co-opera­tive, even though it often took seve­ral years before they were convin­ced of the bene­fits of co-opera­tive work. From over 800,000 indi­vi­dual farms with an average agri­cul­tu­ral area of around 7 hecta­res, over 19,000 LPGs were formed with an average farm size of 245 hecta­res. 85% of all agri­cul­tu­ral land was now farmed by co-operatives.

Socialist agriculture

The LPGs were inde­pen­dent econo­mic units, not an amal­ga­ma­tion of other­wise inde­pen­dent farmers, and as such perfor­med a broad social func­tion for econo­mic, social, and cultu­ral tasks. Their socia­list charac­ter was only reali­sed through their purpose, their working and orga­ni­sa­tio­nal methods and, above all, their firmly inte­gra­ted role within the plan­ned economy of the DDR.

The multi­ple burdens on women farmers and the child labour that was common on family farms were abolished in the LPG. Women and young people became equal members. Equal pay for equal work, regard­less of age and gender, child bene­fits, holi­days, sick pay, health care, regu­la­ted working hours — previously unima­gi­nable achie­ve­ments in agri­cul­ture were made possi­ble by the coope­ra­ti­ves. The LPG became the centre of social and cultu­ral deve­lo­p­ment in the villa­ges. In coope­ra­tion with the coun­cils of the districts and boroughs, roads and resi­den­tial buil­dings were built, libra­ries and cultu­ral centres were main­tai­ned, kinder­gar­tens were crea­ted, sport­ing and cultu­ral events were orga­nised. In the 1960s, there was a sharp increase in the number of employees with a degree in tech­ni­cal and higher educa­tion. A veri­ta­ble educa­tion revo­lu­tion began for the rural population.

Incre­asing coope­ra­tive rela­ti­onships between the LPGs and proces­sing and trading compa­nies deepe­ned inte­gra­tion into the DDR’s plan­ning system and brought it closer to large-scale indus­trial produc­tion. The Agrar-Indus­trie-Verei­ni­gung (AIV), in which LPGs and various indus­tries were orga­ni­sa­tio­nally connec­ted, embo­dies this process of insti­tu­tio­na­li­sed coope­ra­tion most clearly. 13 of these huge produc­tion comple­xes were formed by the end of the DDR. Large-scale produc­tion raised a number of new ques­ti­ons and problems. The sepa­ra­tion of animal and plant produc­tion, which was later judged to be inap­pro­priate, was even­tually correc­ted. Ques­ti­ons such as the limits of scien­ti­fic controll­a­bi­lity of biolo­gi­cally and envi­ron­men­tally depen­dent agri­cul­tu­ral produc­tion remained under discus­sion. Brigade and co-opera­tive meetings, farmers’ congres­ses, repre­sen­ta­ti­ons in the Natio­nal Front, the People’s Cham­ber, the districts and boroughs, and not least the public exch­ange in the media crea­ted the basic condi­ti­ons for deal­ing with problems and contra­dic­tions. Whether they were actively utili­sed for this purpose depen­ded, as so often, not least on the fore­sight of leading cadres.

The return to capitalism

The main focus of the agri­cul­tu­ral trans­for­ma­tion after 1990 was the liqui­da­tion of the LPGs.  They were to give way to the family farming model that prevai­led in West Germany. At that time, 45% of the land farmed by the co-opera­ti­ves was owned by the people. All state-owned land was gradu­ally priva­tised. This was a decisive lever for brea­king up and dismant­ling the LPG struc­tures. Howe­ver, the fact that a large propor­tion of the land contin­ued to be the private property of the farmers in the co-opera­ti­ves meant that they retai­ned the possi­bi­lity of conti­nuing at least parts of the co-opera­ti­ves under capi­ta­list condi­ti­ons. The struc­tu­ral chan­ges that were impo­sed at breakneck speed imme­dia­tely after 1990 led to a veri­ta­ble rural exodus. Of the former 923,000 agri­cul­tu­ral workers in the DDR, 743,900 were laid off by 1993, 4 out of 5 had to leave. The social and cultu­ral infra­struc­ture was destroyed. Young and quali­fied workers in parti­cu­lar left the villages.

Despite the radi­cal capi­ta­list turn­around, the history of the DDR has left its visi­ble mark on agri­cul­tu­ral struc­tures to this day. On average, farms in East Germany culti­vate much larger areas than in the West. While 68% of agri­cul­tu­ral land in the East is farmed on farms with more than 500 hecta­res, this figure is only 2% in the West. Former LPGs, which are conti­nuing at least part of their struc­ture through new legal forms under market economy condi­ti­ons, are being put under further pres­sure by the land specu­la­tion that has long since taken hold in the East. Rising rental fees threa­ten to conti­nu­ally disin­te­grate agri­cul­tu­ral structures.

From 1990 onwards, farmers were once again left to their own devices: Sales diffi­cul­ties, price pres­sure, and market compe­ti­tion brought back exis­ten­tial worries. With the capi­ta­list resto­ra­tion came the “cheap”, mostly migrant harvest workers and farm labou­rers, and growing inequa­lity retur­ned. Land lies fallow as an object of specu­la­tion instead of produ­cing food. Profit has become the deter­mi­ning factor in agri­cul­ture. Although under very diffe­rent circum­s­tances than in 1945, “the land to those who work it” is once again on the agenda in East Germany, as in many parts of the world.

Leave a Comment