Matthew Read
28 February 2025

Table of contents
- Introduction
- The starting point of the People’s Republic (1580 – 1921)
- The beginning of the “general democratic phase” (1921–1928)
- The struggle against Lamaism and Japanese imperialism (1928–1940)
- The construction of socialism in Mongolia (1940 – 1960)
- Integration into the Comecon (1960 – 1990)
- Mongolia and the strategy of “non-capitalist development” in Africa and Asia
Introduction
The Mongolian People’s Republic, founded in 1924, was the second state after the Soviet Union in which the immense working masses seized power from their former exploiters and set out to construct a socialist society. Yet in practically every regard, Mongolia was even more underdeveloped than its Soviet neighbour to the north. The working people were confronted with the brutal feudal rule of both the Mongolian nobility and the Chinese occupiers. Following the 1921 revolution, the Mongolian People’s Revolutionary Party led the country from a backward feudal-theocratic society through a period of democratic transformation towards an agro-industrialized socialist economy. Progressively, and despite many setbacks and challenges, former serfs were lifted out of destitution and saw massive improvements to their living standards. Education and health indicators confirmed this: Mongolia became the first country in Asia to achieve universal literacy, while life expectancy was consistently higher than in similar countries such as India and Nepal.
The Mongolian experience was unique in that the country circumvented the capitalist stage of development entirely. The people’s democratic states in Eastern Europe had all previously passed through a period of capitalist development before constructing socialism. So too had Soviet Russia, to a certain extent. Yet in Mongolia and the Central Asian Soviet Republics, an entirely new path of so-called “non-capitalist development” had been pioneered. In the 1960s and 1970s, Marxist-Leninist development theorists began revisiting Mongolia’s experiences with the conviction that this history could inform development strategies for the former colonies in Africa and Asia. The economies and social structures of these newly independent states had been significantly deformed by colonial rule and exploitation. Could they too circumvent capitalism and advance towards socialism like Mongolia had?
This article provides a rough overview of Mongolia’s revolutionary period and traces out the development strategies of Mongolian Marxists after 1921. Focus is set largely on the early “general democratic phase” (1921–1940) during which the main task was to push back the power of the domestic feudal classes and withstand imperialist aggression from abroad. These initial decades represented the most complicated and decisive period of Mongolia’s revolution. The article then examines how Mongolia constructed a unified socialist planning system and integrated itself into the socialist world economy. The conclusion critically reflects on Mongolia’s role in socialist scholarship on the theory of “non-capitalist development”.
Our research is drawn from the works of Mongolian and Eastern European scholars, as well as statistics from Western historians. Particularly useful were the discussions generated by an international academic conference held in Berlin in 1975, which brought together scholars from seven socialist states. We also interviewed the former deputy prime minister of Mongolia (2012–2014), Dendev Terbishdagva, who was one of hundreds of young Mongolians to study in the German Democratic Republic (DDR). His views on Mongolia’s development and challenges helped us assess the legacy of the socialist period.
The starting point of the People’s Republic (1580 – 1921)
To appreciate the significance of the socialist period, it is necessary to understand the situation in Mongolia prior to the revolution. At the beginning of the 20th century, Mongolian society was dominated a secular and religious aristocracy that amassed their wealth by exploiting “Arats”, the nomadic Mongolian herdsmen. Arats composed over 90 percent of the population, yet they owned only half the country’s livestock. The rest was concentrated in the hands of the nobility, who, prior to the 1921 revolution, accounted for just 7.8 percent of the population. Arats were dependent on and subject to the feudal lords; they were compelled to pay tribute in the form of natural taxes, bonded labour, or indentured servitude.

While the feudal nobles were the decedents of the Genghis Khan era (1162–1227), the Mongolian aristocracy had long ceased to be a powerful force in Asia. By the end of the 14th century, the Ming dynasty had definitively defeated Mongolian attempts to re-subjugate China, and Mongolia descended into a long period of disintegration, as nobles fought amongst themselves for control. In this context of feudal fragmentation and chaos, the Mongolian aristocracy needed to find an ideological framework that could reinforce their exploitation of the Arats. They found a solution in Tibetan Lamaism:
“It was primarily the ruling classes who promoted the introduction of Lamaism. The overall social and political situation in Mongolia in the 16th century made the ground appear fertile for the new religion. Due to the long wars and political turmoil, the country was fragmented into a large number of rulerships, there was no economic and political unity, and the country and its people were completely impoverished. The ruling classes tried to strengthen their influence and power over the people.
Religion – in the form of the Lamaism that had been developed and tested in feudal Tibet – was a suitable means of influencing the people through ideology. The traditional shaman religion, which was rooted in the pre-class society, could not become an effective ideological power factor in feudal Mongolia and therefore had to be replaced by a form of religion adapted to the socio-economic conditions.”1W. König, “Mongolei”, Museum für Völkerkunde zu Leipzig, Leipzig, 1967, pg. 75.
Having emerged in communal society where social structures were relatively egalitarian and based on kinship ties, shamanism was a decentralized and relatively unorganised form of religion. The Lamaism that had developed in Tibet, on the other hand, promoted hierarchical monastic institutions and advanced the idea of a divinely ordained social hierarchy. It was thus better suited to legitimize the noble’s rule over the Arats.
The Mongolian aristocracy began importing Tibetan Lamaism and adapting it to Mongolian traditions. The first monasteries were built in the 1580s and were generously subsidized by the secular nobles. Monasteries received land and livestock and were gifted “Shabinar” (servant families). To encourage the Arats to take up the new religion, the nobles granted privileges to those who attended monastery schools: Lamas were exempt from military service and taxes and sometimes even given livestock as a reward. Lamaism helped to legitimize the continued rule of the feudal lords, but it did not eliminate the internal struggles within the ruling class. The enduring fragmentation of the country ultimately enabled the Manchu Qing dynasty – which had taken control in China (1644–1911) – to subjugate most of Mongolia by the beginning of the 17th century.
With the successful anchoring of Lamaism and the introduction of Manchu feudal law in Mongolia, the Arats now faced double exploitation: by the foreign Qing rulers and by the secular and religious Mongolian lords. The Arats thus fell into two centuries of deprivation and foreign rule, with population numbers steadily declined over time. This situation led to great unrest in the early 20th century. Inspired by the Chinese revolution of 1911, these uprisings grew into a broad national liberation movement. A degree of national autonomy was regained in 1915 after an agreement was reached between Russia, the new Republic of China, and the head of the Lamish church in Mongolia, Bogd Khan. This new Bogd Khanate remained under heavy Chinese influence and was ultimately overthrown in 1919 when China again invaded the country.
The Mongolian national movement regathered its forces and – inspired this time by the success of the Bolsheviks during the October Revolution of 1917 – formed the Mongolian People’s Party (MPP) in June 1920. The new party was organized along democratic centralist principles, and its first programme called for an end to foreign rule and the exploitation of the Arats. At this point, the MPP was a pluralist party held together by the struggle for national liberation; its members included Arats, Lamas, and even nobles.2Of the 225 members in December 1921, roughly 10 percent belonged to the feudal classes. The rest were Arats. The trial period for the nobility and lamas was twice as long as it was for Arats. See R. Bormann “Zur Entstehung un Entwicklung der MRVP in den Jahren von 1918 bis 1940” in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 46. The national question overshadowed the social question during this period. The MPP sent representatives to revolutionary Russia to establish ties with the Bolsheviks, for the Soviet leaders had been the only ardent supporters of Mongolian independence.

Under the command of the MPP, the newly established Mongolian People’s Army (MPA) began repelling Chinese forces from Mongolia. The situation became more complicated when tsarist Baron Roman von Ungern-Sternberg invaded Mongolia in August 1920. Ungern was able to drive the Chinese out of the capital in February 1921 and restored Bogd Khan as monarch. In response, the MPA launched an offensive against the White Russians. Together with the Soviet Red Army, the MPA successfully liberated the capital in July 1921, marking the victory of the Mongolian People’s Revolution. A new government was proclaimed and operated as a constitutional monarchy. Bogd Khan’s powers were limited to those of purely symbolic nature, while feudal taxes and laws around serfdom and servitude were abolished.
The newly independent Mongolia had just 550,000 inhabitants, but was the size of France, Britain, Spain, and Portugal combined. The vast majority of the population lived as nomadic herders in the country’s semi-arid plains.
The beginning of the “general democratic phase” (1921–1928)
Against the background of the Russian Civil War and the anti-Bolshevik invasion by the Western powers and Japan, an intense and often violent struggle broke out within the MPP to determine the future of Mongolia. There was a clear split between the more conservative nationalists and the Marxists. The latter had travelled to Moscow in November 1921 to negotiate an agreement between the new Mongolian government and the Soviet Union. During their visit, the MPP delegation met with Lenin and asked for his advice on how to proceed with the Mongolian revolution. Lenin’s response was noted down by the delegation and helped to strategically orient Mongolian Marxists in the decades ahead:
“Comrade Lenin elaborated on the idea that it was possible and necessary for the MPR to follow a non-capitalist path of development, the main condition for which was hard work on the part of the People’s Revolutionary Party and the Government, so that this work and the increased influence of the Party and the authorities would result in a growth of the number of co-operatives, in the introduction of new forms of economic activity and national culture, and would rally the Arats behind the Party and the Government in the interests of the country’s economic and cultural development. It was only from the islets of the new economic way of life created by the efforts of the Party and the Government that the new non-capitalist economic system of Arat Mongolia would take shape.“3V.I. Lenin, “Talk with a Delegation of the Mongolian People’s Republic” in Lenin Collected Works, Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow. Also available: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/nov/05b.htm
Lenin also encouraged the Mongolians to proceed cautiously and maintain a degree of revolutionary patience. When asked if he thought the MPP should transform itself into a communist party, Lenin responded:
“I should not recommend it, because one party cannot be ‘transformed’ into another.” Comrade Lenin explained the essence of a Communist Party as a party of the proletariat, and said: “The revolutionaries will have to put in a good deal of work in developing state, economic and cultural activities before the herdsman elements become a proletarian mass, which may eventually help to ‘transform’ the People’s Revolutionary Party into a Communist Party. A mere change of signboards is harmful and dangerous.”
After Bogd Khan died in 1924, the Marxists in the MPP seized the moment to gain the upper hand. The government issued a decree forbidding the search for a “new incarnation” of the Khan. At its 3rd Party Congress, the MPP announced that a revolutionary-democratic dictatorship of the labouring Arats would be established under the name of the Mongolian People’s Republic (MPR). The Party declared that the country would pursue a path of “non-capitalist development” (NCD) towards socialism. The MPP was renamed as the Mongolian People’s Revolutionary Party (MPRP) and joined the Communist International. One year later, at the 4th Party Congress, the MPRP fixed scientific socialism as its guiding ideology and adopted a new programme, which laid out a comprehensive strategy of advancing the democratic revolution along non-capitalist lines before beginning with the construction of socialism at a later time.4D. Das, „Die führende Rolle der MRVP während der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 59. The Party identified the poor and middle Arats as the social force driving the NCD process: the government’s policies had to strengthen this class and foster their consciousness.5R. Bormann, pg. 49.

The central tasks of this phase were democratic and anti-feudal in nature. The MPRP initially proceeded slowly so as to not antagonize the former ruling classes before Arat power had been properly consolidated. During the first four years, basic economic infrastructure was built, such as a national bank (a joint venture with the USSR), a new currency, a postal system, and a state trading company.6P. Sukachevin et al., “The Mongolian People’s Republic: Toward a Market Economy”, International Monetary Fund, 1991, pg. 4. Small-scale handicrafts were encouraged to develop, as was simple commodity production amongst the Arats. Trade and domestic commerce were dominated by the private sector, with many trading firms being owned by Chinese and Anglo-American businessmen. To assist the Arats, the MPRP initiated plans to construct livestock protection fences and haymaking stations to feed cattle. The first factories were constructed in the capital with Soviet assistance. By 1928, external trade with the USSR had risen to account for 15 percent of imports and 20 percent of exports.7P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 5. To draw Arats into the management of society, the new constitution established “Khurals” (popular assemblies) as organs of people’s power.
The struggle against Lamaism and Japanese imperialism (1928–1940)
A serious challenge confronting the MPRP was the question of Lamaism and this has been one of the most controversial aspects of Mongolia’s revolutionary period. To understand the MPRP’s approach to Lamaism during the general democratic phase, it is necessary to recognize both the historical role of the clergy within Mongolian society and the international context of the 1920s and 1930s. This was a period of acute international class struggle in which anti-communist forces sought to annihilate the Soviet Union and the wider communist world movement. By 1926/27, two direct threats to Mongolian sovereignty had crystalized: Japanese imperialism and the Kuomintang under Chiang Kai-shek. These developments forced the MPRP and the Comintern to conclude that war was on the horizon and take drastic preparatory measures. The period from 1928 to 1945 was thus a particularly turbulent phase of the revolution, as the MPRP and Comintern struggled to overcome what they self-critically described as their own right-wing and left-wing deviations during this struggle.
By the 20th century, Lamaism had become deeply embedded in Mongolian society, both culturally and economically. Prior to the revolution in 1921, monasteries held a monopoly over education and healthcare services. There was only one single public school with just two teachers and roughly 100 pupils operating in pre-revolutionary Mongolia. All other schools were controlled by the clergy. The almost absolute illiteracy of the Arats meant that clerics were able to exert great influence over the masses. Only 0.5 percent of the total population could read and write in Mongolian. The clergy’s teachings were ideologically reactionary and, what is more, the Lamaist doctrine objectively hindered economic development. Irrational Buddhist principles discouraged basic agricultural practices such as crop cultivation to feed cattle because the killing of living organisms (even plants) was supposedly a sin.

Alongside their cultural role, the monasteries represented a significant economic factor in the country. In 1918, the clergy’s property accounted for more than 20 percent of Mongolia’s wealth (the secular nobility held another 25 percent). Monasteries had accumulated a large portion of the country’s livestock and ran extensive trade and financial operations that exploited poorer and middle Arats. The clergy’s profits were not reinvested productively into the production process, but simply accumulated in the monasteries.
All this led the monasteries to naturally become rallying points for the counterrevolution. Those who sought to retain their privileges in society or destabilize Mongolia from within found co-conspirators in the 700+ monasteries throughout the country. During the early years, the MPRP had implemented soft policies against the monasteries and took a flexible approach towards the tens of thousands of lamas. The most exploitative Lamaist practices (e.g., indentured servitude) were banned immediately, but the monasteries were not expropriated or heavily taxed. The number of lamas in fact increased from 87,300 in 1925 to almost 95,000 by 1928.8J. Sima, „Zur Rolle der Komintern bei der Verteidigung der Generallinie der MRVP Ende der zwanziger und Anfang der dreißiger Jahre“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 241. At this time, the MPRP focused on creating publicly owned infrastructure to break the monasteries’ monopoly on social services. Mass literacy campaigns were initiated, and, by 1930, over 120 schools had been built throughout the country.9U. Schöne, “Die Entwicklung des Volksbildungswesen in der Mongolischen Volksrepublik” in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, pg. 171. The official separation of church and state was declared in 1926.

By the end of the decade, the international situation had deteriorated considerably. Chiang Kai-shek initiated his attack on the Chinese communists in 1926 with the so-called Canton Coup. The Kuomintang government, which consolidated its grip over China by 1928, refused to recognize Mongolia as an independent state. In 1927, Japanese war plans (the so-called “Tanaka Memorial”) had also been leaked to the international media, revealing how Tokyo sought to conquer Mongolia and Manchuria as gateways to taking over China.
Against this background, there was contentious debate within the MPRP about how to proceed with the revolution. The party leadership at the time was upholding a moderate domestic policy towards the nobility and pursuing rapprochement with both Japan and anti-communist China.10J. Sima, pg. 243. The position of the right-wing leadership towards the nobility was expressed by the MPRP’s Chairman, Tseren-Ochiryn Dambadorj, at the 5th Party Congress in 1926:
“The former feudal lords as a political force within the country are a dead weight, incapable of fighting for political power. There is no need to expect any action against the revolutionary order from their side. They are politically dead.“11Ibid., pg. 243.
Left-wing elements within the MPRP were pushing back against this line. Certain party cells, particularly those outside the cities, were calling for more rigorous initiatives to strengthen the Arats and resist the encroaching power of the nobility. This tendency came came to be known as the “Khödöö Opposition” (Opposition of the rural areas) by the mid-1920s.12Ibid., pg.245. An open confrontation broke out at the next party congress in 1927, when the leadership was criticized for “pro-capitalist tendencies”. Yet the leadership managed to defend its position. The left-wing opposition did not yield and secured a first victory at the national trade union congress in September 1928, when they successfully elected a new leadership. The left wing of the mass youth organization was able to do the same a few weeks later. The opposition then united behind the so-called “Platform of the Members of the Left Wing”, which they presented to the MPRP Central Committee.13Ibid., pg. 248.
Alarmed by the internal party conflict and the deteriorating international situation, the Far East Bureau of the Comintern began sending letters to the MPRP’s leadership in 1927 to urge a different course of action. Pavel Mif, the provost of the Comintern’s Sun Yat-sen University in Moscow, wrote that the Mongolian revolutionaries had “eliminated the feudal political order, but had not broken the economic power of the feudal lords and clerics.”14Cited in H. Piazza, “Die Komintern und die MRVP” in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 272. The MPRP’s leadership rejected this analysis and started to break off relations with the Comintern. The Far East Bureau then sent Bohumír Šmeral, a co-founder of the Communist Party of Czechoslovakia, to lead a Comintern delegation at the MPRP’s 7th Party Congress in 1928. Šmeral energetically supported the platform of the left wing, while trying to moderate their accusations against the “right-wing traitors”.15J. Sima, pg. 248. At the Congress, he presented the Comintern’s analysis that the political alliance with the feudal classes had been necessary until 1924 but should now be considered outdated. The nobility had been able to retain their economic power and were beginning to use it to regain political dominance. Mongolia had reached a crossroads: either complete the anti-feudal revolution or allow the feudal lords to retain power and continue conspiring with the Japanese and Chinese.
The clash between the two factions caused the 7th Congress to drag on for over a month and a half. At the closing elections, the left wing won the majority of the seats in the Central Committee and initiated a shift in the party’s line. Following recommendations by the Comintern, the MPRP now set out to strengthen the poorer and middle Arats while curtailing the power of the wealthy. The objective was to two-fold: to break the economic power of the feudal lords and clerics and to rapidly accelerate industrialization by overcoming unproductive feudalist practices in agriculture. Accordingly, over 700 properties belonging to the secular nobility were confiscated and distributed amongst the Arats. Feudal estates were broken up and the land was nationalized, making pastureland free to access for all Arats. Transportation and retail services were nationalized, and the state imposed a monopoly on foreign trade to drive out foreign capital.16S. Nacagdorz, „Das internationalistische Bündnis der werktätigen Araten mit der Arbeiterklasse des siegreichen Sozialismus – ein entscheidender Faktor der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 35.
Taxation laws were completely rewritten in an attempt to alleviate the poorer and middle Arats while increasing taxes on the feudal lords, the clergy, and the richer Arats. This new taxation system was also devised to disincentivize Lamaism: by removing tax privileges for lamas, it discouraged young Mongolians from joining the monasteries. The enormous cattle herds concentrated in the monasteries (representing 24.5 percent of all livestock in 1926) was redistributed to the poorer Arats, who could now supervise the cattle on a contractual basis with the state.17J. Sima, pg. 241. The monasteries themselves were, however, permitted to continue operating as religious institutions.18W. König, pg. 85. The creation of agricultural cooperatives was greatly accelerated. Rather than extending the existing cooperative structures that had been based on basic mutual aid amongst Arats (e.g., sharing the burden of hay harvesting), the authorities now sought to create large communes that would collectivize cattle ownership and crop cultivation on a mass scale. At the same time, the MPRP opened its ranks to masses of applicants.
These policies amounted to an all-out class war against the exploiting classes in Mongolia. While the general orientation was formulated as a response to the counterrevolutionary and imperialist threats, the extent and speed of the new policies proved too great. The new state-run services in transport and retail had been hastily thrown together and struggled to cope with their new tasks. The new tax system backfired, as richer Arats chose to slaughter their livestock rather than pay the higher taxes. Many poorer lamas and workers were left without incomes after the economic activities of the monasteries were curtailed. The private handicraft sector was suffocated out of existence, although no cooperative or state structures existed to replace it. Finally, the collectivisation drive in agriculture had been a failure. The initiative had been inspired by the “Great Break” in the USSR, yet the national conditions in Mongolia’s nomadic agriculture different greatly from those in Soviet Russia. By 1930, over 600 cooperatives and communes had been created out of the hundreds of thousands of privately run Arat operations.19J. Sima, pg. 257. At times, the authorities had equated middle and richer Arats with the feudal nobility and used administrative measures to force entry into communes.
Against this background, discontent spread throughout the countryside and counterrevolutionary forces mobilized to exploit the situation. The unrest climaxed in 1932 when wealthy lamas led a series of armed uprisings against the government. Many of the insurgents rallied supporters by claiming to be supported by Tibetan lamas and the Japanese. They targeted state-owned and cooperative facilities, laying waste to much of the progress achieved since 1924. The MPA was able to subdue the insurgents within a few months, but great economic damage had been done.
Self-critically reflecting on the situation, the MPRP pulled back and reversed many of their measures from 1928. A “New Turn” policy was announced in 1932 to correct the “left-wing deviations” and return to the “general line” the MPRP had set out for the non-capitalist path of development at their 3rd Party Congress in 1924. At an extraordinary plenary session in 1932, the party concluded that too many cadres had believed an “immediate transition to socialism” was possible in Mongolia; they had “mechanically copied the methods of socialist construction that had been applied in the USSR”.20Ibid., pg. 257. The party had oriented itself exclusively around the poorest Arats while isolating itself from the middle and wealthier Arats. To correct these mistakes, the “New Turn” ordered agricultural communes to be dismantled and the private initiatives of the Arats to once again be encouraged. Some of the restrictions levied against the monasteries were lifted. At the same time, the MPRP membership, which had increased four-fold between 1930 and 1932, was greatly reduced to reverse the “ultra-leftist” opening of the party.21Ibid., pg. 260
While these measures helped to stabilize the economy and the social situation, they did not solve the fundamental contradiction between Lamaism and the national-democratic revolution. In 1934 – 10 years after the founding of the People’s Republic – there were still some 80,000 lamas active in hundreds of monasteries across Mongolia.22W. König, pg. 81. The MPRP would have to find a solution to this predicament; organized Lamaism still represented an economic and political obstacle on the path towards socialism.

In the mid-1930s, the conflicts on the world stage intensified even further. Japan invaded Manchuria in 1931 and set up a puppet state that soon began provoking border conflicts with Mongolia. Two years later, fascists took power in Germany and openly declared their intentions to destroy the Soviet Union. In this context, the MPRP decided the country could lose no more time: the “general democratic period” – which represented an inherently volatile and thus vulnerable transitionary phase of the revolution – had to be concluded. The government introduced a massive state-led industrialization initiative that led to a 22-fold increase in industrial output between 1933 to 1940.23B. Sirendyb, „Einige Probleme aus der Geschichte der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR zum Sozialismus“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 25. Strict taxes were once again levied against monasteries as part of a wider crackdown on Lamaism. After Japan’s full-scale invasion of China in 1937 and its attacks on the Soviet Union in 1938, unsparing purges swept through the MPRP and state apparatus to target alleged Japanese collaborators. A violent crackdown on the clergy dealt a definitive blow to Lamaism. Just weeks after these purges had been suspended, Japanese troops launched attacks on Mongolia. In the Battles of Khalkhin Gol, Mongolian and Soviet forces were ultimately able to defeat the Japanese invaders and drive them out of the country.

By the end of the 1930s, the economic and social power of the feudal classes had been completely broken. The monasteries were now fully expropriated, and all livestock was in the hands of working Arats. The MPRP had, however, concluded from the mistakes of the late 1920s that agriculture was still too underdeveloped for cooperative structures, so cattle remained under the private ownership of the herdsmen. Foreign capital had been successfully pushed out of the economy: while in 1926 foreign firms had controlled over 60 percent of Mongolia’s total exports, by 1929 this number had deceased to 14,5 percent. At the end of the 1930s, foreign ownership was practically eliminated.24J. Sima, pg. 241.
During its 10th Party Congress in 1940, under the shadow of the Second World War, the MPRP declared that the tasks laid out in the second party programme from 1925 had been achieved: the general democratic phase was complete, and the path of non-capitalist development could no longer be reversed.25R. Bormann, pg. 53. A solid industrial base had been established, with industry now accounting for over 20 percent of the country’s total production.26W. König, pg. 86. For a country with practically zero manufacture prior to the revolution, this represented a remarkable feat of modernization in just 16 years. The 10th Congress thus adopted a third political programme to set out the tasks for the coming phase of socialist construction. The collective nature of the Party’s leadership was also reinstated following the period of intense internal purges (1937–39). At the 8th Grand Khural (national parliament) in 1940, a new constitution was adopted to reflect the new stage of the revolution and the transformation of Mongolia’s class structure:
“The Mongolian People’s Republic is an independent state of the working people (the Arat herdsmen, the working class, and the intelligentsia), who have thrown off the imperialist and feudal yoke, ensuring a non-capitalist path of development for the country to pave the way for socialism.”27D. Sodnomgombo, „Die grundlegenden Veränderungen in der Klassenstruktur der MVR als Ergebnis der Überwindung der sozialen Widersprüche in der Übergangsperiode von Feudalismus zum Sozialismus“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 101.
The general democratic phase represented the most turbulent period of Mongolia’s revolution and the 1930s were undoubtedly the culmination point of this process, when the struggle between the revolutionaries and the aristocracy escalated into full-blown class warfare. Today, dominant historical accounts often decontextualize the MPRP’s policies to paint the picture of an inexplicably tyrannical ruling party. This ahistorical approach not only downplays the brutal realities of feudal rule in pre-revolutionary Mongolia, but also ignores the role played by the secular and religious aristocracy in actively resisting social progress for the labouring Arats after 1921. What is more, one only has to look to China – where Japanese imperialism pillaged and slaughtered millions of civilians while allying with collaborationist forces in the Kuomintang – to see that the threats facing Mongolia in the 1930s were very real.
Lamaism posed a particularly difficult challenge for the revolution because it was so deeply entrenched in Mongolian society. It was one thing to break the economic and political power of the religious aristocracy, but it was another to push back the cultural influence of Buddhism. While the MPRP developed public infrastructure (e.g., schools, medical facilities, etc.) to reduce the influence of the monasteries, the government also prohibited cultural traditions at the lowest levels (e.g., banning shrines, etc.) in its attempt to encourage rationalism. It was not uncommon for such policies to inadvertently provoke the ire of sections of the population. Like many other revolutionary states in the 20th century, the Mongolian People’s Republic struggled to navigate the irrational and often oppressive traditions of the past.
The construction of socialism in Mongolia (1940 – 1960)
The years of the Second World War marked an interlude in Mongolia’s development, with assistance from the USSR drying up. Mongolia was financing military units for the Soviet war effort and supplied the USSR with food, raw materials, clothing, and half a million military horses. Following the defeat of German and Japanese imperialism in 1945, the MPRP resumed plans to begin with the construction of socialism. The first five-year plan was drafted in 1947, with a focus on developing cattle breeding. This was by far the largest sector of the economy and thus initially set the tempo of all other sectors. 90 percent of Mongolia’s cattle was in the hands of individual Arats during these years. The government sought to encourage an increase of livestock while also laying the groundwork for the eventual establishment of large-scale agricultural cooperatives. Tax benefits and loans helped to foster the private operations of the Arats.28P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6. The state also launched initiatives to increase access to modern equipment and create new veterinarian and hay harvesting stations.29P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6 and D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 106. By the end of the first five-year period in 1952, the number of livestock had increased by almost 9 percent.30H. Siebeck „Die MVRP – die führende Kraft der sozialistischen Revolution in der MVR (1940 bis zur Gegenwart)“ in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 56.
During this post-war period, Mongolia’s industries also made a significant step forward: between 1940 and 1950, gross industrial production increased by 285 percent.31D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 106. The sector was dominated by light industries for the processing of agricultural products. In 1947, consumer goods accounted for 76 percent of industrial production. The Party now set out to expand Department 1 (the spheres of production that produce new means of production) to accelerate the growth of Mongolia’s economy. The share of industrial goods in total production thereafter increased from 24.3 percent (1947) to 39.9 percent (1957) and finally to 50.9 percent (1960). Alongside the development of heavy industry, transport infrastructure was greatly expanded. The Trans-Mongolian Railway (completed in 1955) helped to deepen the economic links with the USSR and other socialist states.

A core component of socialist construction in Mongolia was the reorganization of agriculture into a cooperative-based sector. After the bitter lessons of the early 1930s, the MPRP had only encouraged basic cooperation amongst the Arats, who worked as individual petty commodity producers selling goods on the market to each other and the state. Yet the conditions in Mongolia had changed significantly since then. The industries had made significant strides, and a system of comprehensive economic planning had been introduced in 1947. To continue along the path to socialism, it was deemed necessary to both integrate agriculture into the planning system and introduce a rational distribution of the labour force, much of which was currently tied up in the inefficient practice of private cattle rearing.
In the early 1950s, the MPRP began to lay the foundations for greater cooperation in agriculture by introducing management and accounting training along with preferential tax rates for cooperatives.32P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6. As the decade progressed, it became clear that the system of individual petty commodity production was slowing down the Mongolian economy. For almost the entire period between 1941 and 1959, the plan targets for animal products were not reached.33D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 107. At the 12th Party Congress in 1954, the MPRP attributed the slow progress in agriculture to the fact that the cattle breeding sector was run by hundreds of thousands of scattered petty producers. Such relations of production prevented the effective introduction of modern technology and methods in agriculture. This situation represented, as the Mongolian historian D. Sodnomgombo concluded, a “non-antagonistic contradiction between the economic sectors”.34Ibid., pg. 108.
The cooperative movement was thus resumed in 1956. At this time, petty commodity producing Arats made up 73.9 percent of the population.35S. K. Roscin, “Der Leninsche Genossenschaftsplan und die Erfahrungen der MVR” in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 313. Since land had already been nationalized in 1928, the central question was the degree to which Mongolia’s livestock and harvesting operations should be collectivised. By the end of the second five-year plan in 1958, over 200,000 private Arat operations had been merged into 700 negdels (agricultural cooperatives).36S. K. Roscin, “Die sozialistische Landwirtschaft in der MVR“ in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 96, and P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6. Roughly 70 percent of the country’s livestock was jointly owned by and cared for in the negdels, while 24 percent continued to be privately owned by members of the cooperatives who could breed them for individual use.37The remaining cattle was owned by state farms. “Individual [cooperative] members were permitted to own livestock. In mountain steppe pasture areas, ten head of livestock per person, up to fifty head per household, were allowed. In desert regions, fifteen head per person, up to seventy-five head per household, were permitted. Private plots also were allowed for [coopertive] farmers.” S. K. Roscin, “Die sozialistische Landwirtschaft in der MVR“, pg.96, and R. Worden and A. M. Savada, “Mongolia: A Country Study”, GPO for the Library of Congress, Washington, 1989: https://countrystudies.us/mongolia/53.htm As members of negdels, Arats also had the right to run their own private plots.

The completion of the agricultural cooperative movement was identified as a major milestone in Mongolia’s construction of socialism. The 13th Party Congress in 1958 concluded that the country had been “transformed from a purely cattle-breeding country into an agro-industrialised state.”28D. Sodnomgombo, pg.104. After a nationwide debate, a new constitution was adopted in 1960 to reflect the completion of the non-capitalist path of development. The People’s Republic was now described as “a socialist state of the workers, the cooperatively organized Arats, and the working intelligentsia”. In accordance with the industrialization of the country, the proportion of working-class representation within both the Party and the national assembly grew relative to the proportion of Arat representation.

Industrialization and collectivisation had major impacts on Mongolian society. The size of the working class grew from just 14,800 (1940) to 74,200 (1959), while the share of the labour force engaged in agriculture dropped from 90 percent (1940) to 60 percent (1960).39D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 104, and R. Worden and A. M. Savada. Only 2 percent of Mongolia’s population had lived in urban areas before the 1921 revolution, but that number increased to over 40 percent by 1963.40W. König, pg. 32.
Compared with the other socialist states, Mongolia’s industries were still rudimentary, but this modernization drive was highly significant for living and education standards in the country. By the 1960s, illiteracy had been practically eliminated. Children were enrolled in primary education and thousands of young Mongolians were training to become engineers, doctors, veterinarians, economists, etc. Comprehensive health care initiatives helped to raise hygiene standards and vaccinate people against preventable diseases. With the establishment of agricultural cooperatives, the rural population was also guaranteed a stable income and Arats were entitled to holidays and pensions. These new social rights were achieved against the background of a rapidly growing society. While the size of the population gradually declined under feudalism in the centuries prior to the revolution, Mongolia’s population doubled between 1918 and 1962, from 542,000 to over 1 million. By the end of the socialist era in 1990, it had increased fourfold.
Integration into the Comecon (1960 – 1990)
While the collectivisation drive had not been easy, the MPRP’s economic rationale proved well-founded. The integration of agriculture into a unified socialized national economy laid the basis for impressive economic growth in the 1960s. Industrial production per capita increased by 240 percent over the course of the 3rd and 4th five-years plans (1962–1972). This, in turn, helped advance the mechanization of agriculture.41G.S. Matveeva, „Die Schaffung der materiell-technischen Basis in der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 71. Arats released from the labour-intensive private cattle breeding operations now made up the workforce for the new industries.
A major factor in Mongolia’s pronounced economic development after the Second World War was its ties with the other socialist states. Viewed from the perspective of profitability, Mongolia’s social and climatic conditions made the country an unattractive destination for foreign investments. While the country was rich in natural resources such as copper and coal, a considerable capital outlay was required for extraction and processing. The lack of domestic technology and expertise made it impossible to establish extractive industries alone. This reality plagues capitalist Mongolia today.
During the socialist period, however, the People’s Republic had been able to delink from the capitalist world economy and move beyond a dependency on foreign capital. By 1960, trade with the socialist bloc already accounted for 94 percent of Mongolia’s exports and 76 percent of imports.42P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6. Finance for development was coming from the socialist bloc at very favourable rates. Most importantly, socialist partners were not running private operations in Mongolia to siphons off the country’s wealth but were instead supporting publicly owned or joint venture enterprises. This meant that the country’s surplus product could be accumulated in a planned manner and reinvested in the economy to expand the industrial base and fund social progress.
The socialist trade relations took on a qualitatively new character after 1962, when Mongolia became the first non-European state to join the socialist bloc’s economic community, the Council for Mutual Economic Assistance (Comecon). This shift from bilateral to multilateral trade relations meant that the Mongolian economy could be gradually integrated into a socialist international division of labour. The planned transfer of knowledge and technology that followed helped to propel the material and technical basis of the Mongolian economy. Agricultural complexes, geology laboratories, and mining operations were set up with the help of the other socialist states.43Ibid., pg. 6.

In capitalist world trade, it is typical for an industrialized capitalist power to import primary commodities from a former colony and export manufactured goods in return. The serves to deepen relations of dependency, as the former colony is not only prevented from industrializing, but also suffers a deterioration in the terms of trade over time. Understanding this reality, the more developed socialist states did not seek to simply buy raw materials and supply consumer goods to less developed states in Asia and Africa. Rather, they invested in (publicly owned or joint venture) infrastructure and processing industries on the ground to foster long-term development. In Mongolia, this pattern could be seen in the economy’s trade structure. The share of machinery and equipment in total imports from the USSR increased from just 7.9 percent in 1946 to over 55 percent in 1972.44V.D. Tichomirov „Einige Probleme der ökonomischen Zusammenarbeit der MVR mit den sozialistischen Staaten“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 412. At the same time, the volume of processed and semi-processed goods exported to the USSR increased dramatically, while the relative share of raw material exports decreased.
Comecon’s objective was to raise and equal out the level of development of all its member states. This did not, however, entail replicating the economic structures of the more industrialized states in the less developed states. Instead, structures were to be developed that corresponded to the national conditions in each state. In this way, “socialist economic integration” would increase productivity and per capita income across the board, with each member specializing in a particular sector. As an “agro-industrialised state”, Mongolia was to be assisted in electrification and the processing of food and animal by-products (wool, leather, skins, etc.). Long-term credits and joint ventures helped to construct entirely new processing factories. By the end of its first decade in Comecon, the People’s Republic was already covering 20 percent of the socialist bloc’s meat imports and 10 percent of its wool imports.45Ibid., pg. 413. Planned economic integration with the socialist bloc was helping to drive Mongolia’s transition from an agrarian country to an industrialized state:

The transfer of knowledge and technology was at the centre of the socialist states’ relations with Mongolia. By 1973, some 17,000 Mongolians had received training in the USSR, with thousands more studying in other socialist states. While Comecon still represented a rudimentary form of international division of labour by the 1980s, it played a key role in facilitating Mongolia’s development. The country saw a remarkable pace of industrialization during this period, with gross industrial output rising almost six-fold between 1960 and 1980.46P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 8. The Sino-Soviet split that erupted in the early 1960s was undoubtedly detrimental to Mongolia’s economy. Political relations between Ulaanbaatar and Beijing became extremely tense, and Mongolia lost a vital trading partner directly on its border. The Trans-Mongolian Railway had linked Beijing to the USSR and would have greatly contributed to Comecon’s potential.

Being free from dependency on the capitalist world market, Mongolia’s planned economy did not suffer from recessions or stagnation and was able to grow continuously, despite the oil crises affecting much of the rest of the world. After the imposition of capitalism in 1990, Mongolia was largely deindustrialized and has been repeatedly stricken by the boom bust cycle. As Dendev Terbishdagva, the former deputy prime minister of Mongolia (2012–2014), recalled:
“We simply copied capitalism [from the West]. We did not consider the national conditions in Mongolia: the historical development of our country, the nomadic sector in our economy, how many inhabitants we have, and so on. We simply replicated [the West]. […] Enterprises were privatized. That was in my view the first major mistake. Many Mongolians lost their jobs. Highly skilled and trained individuals landed on the streets. The industries were destroyed. Some people managed to buy businesses and take them abroad and thereby became very rich. Others lost everything. There was suddenly a huge inequality in Mongolia. […] Agricultural was also ruined. Prior to 1990, we were exporting wheat. By 2000, we had to import 85 percent of our wheat from Japan and the USA. Within the space of 10 years, we ruined everything. This is what happened after we listened to the World Bank advisors that came to Mongolia. They had never been to our country. They knew nothing about the structure of socialist society and the nomadic economy. It was the same in Africa and Latin America. They told us that everything we built had to be ruined, and in the end, they ruined it very well.”47D. Terbishdagva, in discussion with the IFDDR. July 2024. Ulaanbaatar.
Mongolia and the strategy of “non-capitalist development” in Africa and Asia
The Mongolian government’s announcement in 1960 that the country had completed the non-capitalist path of development coincided with the “Year of Africa”, when 17 African states secured their political independence. When searching for ways out of the maldevelopment imposed by colonialism, many of these young governments were interested to learn from the industrialization strategies of the Soviet Union and other socialist states. The starting conditions now confronting anti-imperialist governments in Africa and Asia were similar to those confronting the MPRP in 1921: foreign occupation had greatly distorted the structure of the economy, while (semi-)feudal forces stood in the way of industry and social progress. In 1960, the communist world movement elaborated on the theoretical framework of non-capitalist development (NCD) and advanced the position that this path towards socialism was now open to new anti-imperialist states such as Egypt, Mali, Guinea, and Ghana.48See the “Moscow Declaration of 1960”, signed by 81 communist and workers’ parties: https://www.marxists.org/history/international/comintern/sino-soviet-split/other/1960statement.htm
The question thus arose as to how the Mongolian experience could inform non-capitalist strategies in Africa and Asia. There were initially two divergent lines in socialist scholarship: those who argued Mongolia’s experience represented a “basic model” that all states pursuing this strategy should follow or whose who believed these experiences had no relevance for the newly liberated states.49C. Mährdel, „Die Erfahrung der MRVP im revolutionären Prozess nichtkapitalistischer Entwicklung zum Sozialismus und revolutionär-demokratische Parteien der heute sozialistisch orientierten Länder Afrikas: Bemerkungen zu einem historischen Vergleich“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 459. By the end of the 1960s, a more nuanced analysis had been settled on, which emphasised that while there were general characteristics of NCD, the specific policies and pace of this process would differ in each state according to the national conditions. Indeed, mechanically copying policies would lead to the same mistakes the MPRP made in the late 1920s.
Against this background, scholars and political cadres from seven socialist states convened in Berlin in 1975 for a conference entitled “The Revolutionary Path of the Mongolian People’s Republic to Socialism: Problems of Circumventing the Capitalist stage of Development”. It was jointly hosted by Berlin’s Humboldt University, Leipzig’s Karl Marx University, and the DDR’s Central Council for Asian, African, and Latin American Sciences, with participants coming from the Soviet Union, the Mongolian PR, the PR Bulgaria, the DR Vietnam, the PR Poland, and the ČSSR. Their objective was to draw out the lessons from this history and understand how the Mongolian revolutionaries overcame the specific challenges they faced.
The participants agreed that the general character of the Mongolian revolution was the same as the revolutions unfolding in many African and Asian states: national and democratic, anti-imperialist and anti-feudal. In democratizing society and the economy, these states would have to contend with the bitter resistance of reactionary forces (like Lamaism in Mongolia) and external threats. To circumvent or break off capitalist relations, the revolutionary political parties would have to secure state power and gradually draw the working masses into the management of society. For B. Sirendyb, professor and president of Mongolia’s Academy of Sciences, there were four major factors that contributed to his country’s success:
- The political support of the communist world movement and the economic and military assistance of the socialist states
- The political leadership of the MPRP
- The people’s democratic state power
- The involvement of the popular masses in solving social and economic problems
The subjective factor was key here. NCD would not develop spontaneously as capitalist relations did out of feudalism. This complicated path to socialism required the leadership of a party with a scientifically grounded programme. In the context of colonial occupation and feudal exploitation, this party would not directly emerge as a vanguard of the proletariat, as the communist parties operating in Europe had. Instead, the party would evolve over time, from a mass anti-colonial party towards a vanguard of the working people. When the Mongolian People’s Party had been founded in 1920, its membership consisted of Arats, clerics, and nobles. Only after an intense struggle was the Marxist-Leninist inspired Arat faction able to secure victory. Over the course of further struggles in the following decades, the party and state power continued to evolve, progressively taking on a proletarian character. In this vein, D. Sodnomgombo from Mongolia’s Institute of History remarked:
“In connection with the fundamental changes in class relations, not only the nature but also the function of the political superstructure changed. Proof of this is the fact that the revolutionary-democratic dictatorship of the labouring Arats was transformed into the dictatorship of the working class, and the formerly revolutionary-democratic people’s party was transformed into a party of the Marxist-Leninist type.”50D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 101.
These reflections led DDR scholar Christian Mährdel to conclude that – on a very general level – the Africa’s anti-imperialist governments of the 1960s were in a similar state to the MPRP in the 1920s and 1930s.51C. Mährdel, pg. 466. Yet the conditions confronting these governments were far more complex than those confronting the MPRP. The socialist-oriented states in Africa and Asia often belonged to what the UN called the “least developed countries” (LDC). They were integrated into the capitalist world economy to a far greater degree than Mongolia had been in the 1920s. Their trade and their main economic sectors were dominated by European or US-American corporations. At the same time, the African states were geographically isolated from the socialist bloc. The influence of the imperialist powers was thus far greater. Although the attendees of the conference did not discuss this point, it is also important to note that the Comintern – which had played such an important role in guiding the MPRP – was never reconstituted after its dissolution in 1943.
The USSR’s economic and military assistance for the Mongolian People’s Republic had been pivotal. The Trans-Mongolian Railway represented a direct economic line to the socialist bloc. The anti-imperialist African states did not have this privilege. They were encircled by hostile states pursuing a different path of development. Comecon membership, which helped propel Mongolia’s development after 1960, was never granted to the socialist-oriented states in Africa. The most promising candidate had been Mozambique. When Maputo applied to join the organization in 1980, it enjoyed ardent support from Berlin because the German Democratic Republic had been working hard to establish closer economic ties.52The GDR accounted for just over 8 percent of Mozambique’s exports and 5.5 percent of its imports in 1980. See P. Vannemann, “Soviet strategy in Southern Africa: Gorbachev’s pragmatic approach”, Hoover Press, Stanford, 1980. 80 percent of Mozambique’s exports were still destined for the capitalist world market at the end of the 1970s, so this was a prime opportunity to reduce the country’s neocolonial dependency on the West. Yet the other Eastern European states in Comecon voted against admission. This was likely because the other states were less developed than the DDR and were already struggling with their own economic difficulties at the time. Mozambique was left with little choice but to turn to the West: it joined the International Monetary Fund in 1984 and opened relations with West Germany, thus deepening its dependency even further.
When the communist world movement had first formulated the possibility of NCD in 1920, Lenin emphasized this would require “the Soviet governments come to [the former colonies’] aid with all the means at their disposal”.53V.I. Lenin, “Second Congress of the Communist International”. Available: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1920/jul/x03.htm This was the crux of the issue. The socialist bloc was unable – and, to a certain extent, unwilling – to live up to this duty. Many scholars at the 1975 conference repeatedly emphasized the role of the Soviet Union’s assistance in Mongolia’s development, but only a few were willing to admit the limitations of their own world system:
“Even if the power and influence of the socialist community of states is constantly increasing in our time, the all-round influence that could be achieved in concrete terms at that time [in Mongolia] is not yet achievable today (and for a longer period of time) in relation to the socialist-oriented forces in Africa and Asia, and the disentanglement of these countries from the system of the capitalist world economy cannot be achieved so swiftly.“54C. Mährdel, pg. 460.
Rather than addressing this dilemma head on, a growing tendency within the communist world movement sought to capitulate before it and abandon the commitment to the anti-imperialist struggle in Africa and Asia. This could also be seen in the stagnation of the Comecon’s plans for international economic integration. Many socialist states in Eastern Europe increasingly integrated themselves into the capitalist world economy by the late 1970s and 1980s. Left uncorrected, the political consequences of this dynamic culminated in the so-called “new thinking” policies under Mikhail Gorbachev. Under the guise of “pragmatism”, Soviet scholars and diplomats such a Karen Brutents and Aleksandr Yakovlev spearheaded an effort to reduce Soviet support for socialist-oriented states such as Angola, Mozambique, and Afghanistan.
Footnotes
[1] W. König, “Mongolei”, Museum für Völkerkunde zu Leipzig, Leipzig, 1967, pg. 75.
[2] Of the 225 members in December 1921, roughly 10 percent belonged to the feudal classes. The rest were Arats. The trial period for the nobility and lamas was twice as long as it was for Arats. See R. Bormann “Zur Entstehung un Entwicklung der MRVP in den Jahren von 1918 bis 1940” in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 46.
[3] V.I. Lenin, “Talk with a Delegation of the Mongolian People’s Republic” in Lenin Collected Works, Progress Publishers, 1971, Moscow. Also available: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1921/nov/05b.htm
[4] D. Das, „Die führende Rolle der MRVP während der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 59.
[5] R. Bormann, pg. 49.
[6] P. Sukachevin et al., “The Mongolian People’s Republic: Toward a Market Economy”, International Monetary Fund, 1991, pg. 4.
[7] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 5.
[8] J. Sima, „Zur Rolle der Komintern bei der Verteidigung der Generallinie der MRVP Ende der zwanziger und Anfang der dreißiger Jahre“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 241.
[9] U. Schöne, “Die Entwicklung des Volksbildungswesen in der Mongolischen Volksrepublik” in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, pg. 171.
[10] J. Sima, pg. 243.
[11] Ibid., pg. 243.
[12] Ibid., pg.245.
[13] Ibid., pg. 248.
[14] Cited in H. Piazza, “Die Komintern und die MRVP” in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 272.
[15] J. Sima, pg. 248.
[16] S. Nacagdorz, „Das internationalistische Bündnis der werktätigen Araten mit der Arbeiterklasse des siegreichen Sozialismus – ein entscheidender Faktor der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 35.
[17] J. Sima, pg. 241.
[18] W. König, pg. 85.
[19] J. Sima, pg. 257.
[20] Ibid., pg. 257.
[21] Ibid., pg. 260
[22] W. König, pg. 81.
[23] B. Sirendyb, „Einige Probleme aus der Geschichte der nichtkapitalistischen Entwicklung der MVR zum Sozialismus“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 25.
[24] J. Sima, pg. 241.
[25] R. Bormann, pg. 53.
[26] W. König, pg. 86.
[27] D. Sodnomgombo, „Die grundlegenden Veränderungen in der Klassenstruktur der MVR als Ergebnis der Überwindung der sozialen Widersprüche in der Übergangsperiode von Feudalismus zum Sozialismus“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 101.
[28] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6.
[29] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6 and D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 106.
[30] H. Siebeck „Die MVRP – die führende Kraft der sozialistischen Revolution in der MVR (1940 bis zur Gegenwart)“ in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 56.
[31] D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 106.
[32] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6.
[33] D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 107.
[34] Ibid., pg. 108.
[35] S. K. Roscin, “Der Leninsche Genossenschaftsplan und die Erfahrungen der MVR” in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 313.
[36] S. K. Roscin, “Die sozialistische Landwirtschaft in der MVR“ in Die Mongolische Volksrepublik, Dietz Verlag, Berlin, 1982, pg. 96, and P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6.
[37] The remaining cattle was owned by state farms. “Individual [cooperative] members were permitted to own livestock. In mountain steppe pasture areas, ten head of livestock per person, up to fifty head per household, were allowed. In desert regions, fifteen head per person, up to seventy-five head per household, were permitted. Private plots also were allowed for [coopertive] farmers.” S. K. Roscin, “Die sozialistische Landwirtschaft in der MVR“, pg.96, and R. Worden and A. M. Savada, “Mongolia: A Country Study”, GPO for the Library of Congress, Washington, 1989: https://countrystudies.us/mongolia/53.htm
[38] D. Sodnomgombo, pg.104.
[39] D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 104, and R. Worden and A. M. Savada.
[40] W. König, pg. 32.
[41] G.S. Matveeva, „Die Schaffung der materiell-technischen Basis in der MVR“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 71.
[42] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 6.
[43] Ibid., pg. 6.
[44] V.D. Tichomirov „Einige Probleme der ökonomischen Zusammenarbeit der MVR mit den sozialistischen Staaten“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 412.
[45] Ibid., pg. 413.
[46] P. Sukachevin et al., pg. 8.
[47] D. Terbishdagva, in discussion with the IFDDR. July 2024. Ulaanbaatar.
[48] See the “Moscow Declaration of 1960”, signed by 81 communist and workers’ parties: https://www.marxists.org/history/international/comintern/sino-soviet-split/other/1960statement.htm
[49] C. Mährdel, „Die Erfahrung der MRVP im revolutionären Prozess nichtkapitalistischer Entwicklung zum Sozialismus und revolutionär-demokratische Parteien der heute sozialistisch orientierten Länder Afrikas: Bemerkungen zu einem historischen Vergleich“ in Der revolutionäre Weg der Mongolischen Volksrepublik zum Sozialismus, Akademie-Verlag, Berlin, 1978, pg. 459.
[50] D. Sodnomgombo, pg. 101.
[51] C. Mährdel, pg. 466.
[52] The GDR accounted for just over 8 percent of Mozambique’s exports and 5.5 percent of its imports in 1980. See P. Vannemann, “Soviet strategy in Southern Africa: Gorbachev’s pragmatic approach”, Hoover Press, Stanford, 1980.
[53] V.I. Lenin, “Second Congress of the Communist International”. Available: https://www.marxists.org/archive/lenin/works/1920/jul/x03.htm
[54] C. Mährdel, pg. 460.